ISSN (Print) - 0012-9976 | ISSN (Online) - 2349-8846

A+| A| A-

Road Rationing and Economic Gains

An Assessment of Delhi’s Odd-Even Formula

The Delhi government’s move to allow only alternate use of cars with odd and even registration numbers from 1 January 2016 is a step in the right direction. However, even as such command and control measures will be difficult to sustain, the gains made from these measures will only wane over time. What are needed are long-term measures with strong economic incentives to ensure favourable outcomes for better quality of air and environment—indeed this involves strengthening public transportations systems.

The recent decision of the Delhi government to permit private vehicles with odd or even registration numbers to run on alternate days has created a stir. The policy envisages reducing the number of vehicles on Delhi roads by about 50%, which is expected to reduce the level of air pollution in the city. The policy has attracted appreciation from quite a few quarters on grounds of improvement in environmental quality. However, many look at it with dismay as they have no inkling of how to manage commuting when the new policy comes into effect. The magnitude of the problem can be imagined if we visualise a scenario where about 42.4 lakh private vehicles will be banned from plying on road[i] on any given day. People commuting in these vehicles will have to be accommodated in the existing alternative modes such as buses and the metro. The adjustment period is too short as it has taken effect from 1 January 2016. The alternative to private vehicles, that is, the public transport system in Delhi, is inadequate, irregular, and over-crowded as usual.

Against this backdrop this article examines the economic gains of the new policy decision and explores the possibility of attaining the policy objective through alternative means.

Private Vehicle Externalities

Undeniably, commuting in private vehicles provides autonomy to people and enhances their productivity by saving on travel time. In addition, it saves them from jostling with the crowd, provides a sense of security—more so at odd hours—and at times enhances their social status. Excessive numbers of vehicles, however, leads to congestion on roads as road space becomes a scarce commodity and adds costs to the economy (Small and Verhoef 2007). In such a situation, the positive aspects of owning a vehicle, considered a private virtue, turns out to be a social vice. Expectedly, the adverse effects are too many. First and foremost, it adds to air pollution and global warming. In the case of Delhi, the contribution of vehicles to air pollution is quite high. Certain studies estimate it to be up to 80% of the total (Gurjar et al 2004). Second, base noise levels in the city have exceeded acceptable standards.[ii] According to Banerjee et al (2008: 165) motor vehicles are the main source of urban noise emission: “The growing vehicle population gives rise to unrestrained noise pollution and associated health effects and can cause both short term as well as long term psychological and physiological disorders.” Third, delays due to traffic jams and uncertainty in reaching destination in time gives rise to considerable stress in human beings with many instances of road rage being noticed in recent years. Fourth, seen from an economic perspective, congestion on roads results in loss of man-hours as travel time gets longer. Fifth, slow-moving traffic leads to higher fuel expenditure at the household level and larger imports of crude oil at the macro level, which has implications for valuable foreign exchange.

It is discernible that the use of a private vehicle could have a bearing on the costs borne by others, popularly known as “negative externalities” in economic terminology. While costs to the owner/user of the vehicle is limited to expenses on fuel and maintenance, costs to society are the rise in health expenditure and economic wastages. This results in a divergence between social cost and private cost, the former being greater than the latter. Such a scenario gives rise to the classic “free-rider problem,” where the economic agents causing negative externalities do not bear the full cost of their action.

Policy Options

In order to deal with the free-rider problem, existing literature suggests three policy options, namely, moral suasion, command and control (CAC), and economic incentives. Under moral suasion, people are persuaded to carry out environment-friendly practices. Through several advertisements and awareness campaigns, the government aims at educating people. Campaign for use of public transport (Ab Bus Karein—let us take a bus) and car-pooling are two prominent examples that fall into this category. A limitation of this approach is that it leaves decision-making to the good sense of individuals; no penalty is imposed for non-compliance. The CAC measures are direct regulation by the government concerning controlling vehicle speed, traffic movement, fuel use, emission levels and safety norms. Unlike moral suasion, CAC measures are coercive and invite penalties. The economic incentives pertain to the use of taxes and subsidies to attain the set objectives and leave decision-making to economic rationality of the person concerned.

For reduction of air pollution several CAC-type measures, such as use of lead-free fuel, conversion to CNG, and tightening of emission standards have been introduced. In addition, penalties for violation of traffic rules have been hiked manifold. Road tax and parking charges, which are one-time payments at the time of registration of vehicles, have been increased to make private vehicles costlier and thus discourage people from going for private vehicles. Studies show that certain parameters of air pollution witnessed a decline after conversion to CNG (Kathuria 2005) but the benefits have waned over the years. In a recent noting, the Delhi High Court observed that air pollution levels in Delhi have reached “alarming proportions” and it is akin to living in a “gas chamber.”[iii]

The signals given by the policy measures however have not been strong enough to discourage people from buying private vehicles. The number of vehicles per 1,000 people in Delhi has gone up to 487, implying approximately one vehicle for every two persons.[iv] Two factors appear to have more than offset the gains of the policy measures followed so far. First, Delhi has a very high per capita income, Rs 2,40,849 in 2014–15. This tremendous purchasing power in the hands of people, allows most households to buy a vehicle.[v] Second, public transport systems are weak, thereby compelling people to fend for themselves. As per the Government of Delhi (2015), there are 88,27,431 vehicles as of March 2015. Of these, 64.36% are motorcycles and scooters, while 31.61% are cars and jeeps—together they make up 96%. The share of buses is a meagre 0.22%, while taxies and auto-rickshaws comprise nearly 1% each. It is worth mentioning that there is a consistent decline in the share of buses in Delhi over the years. During 1991–92 there were 20,201 buses which increased to 41,483 by 2000–01, and subsequently declined to 19,729 in 2014–15. The decline is not only for private buses, the fleet size of the Delhi Transport Corporation (DTC) has also declined. The DTC is running on a perpetual loss[vi] to be funded by the state government and its expansion has not been a priority. Introduction of metro rail has improved public transport systems to some extent, although it has become very crowded of late.

Odd–Even Logic

Over the years, the Delhi government has recognised the congestion problem emanating from an excess number of vehicles in the city and in order to ameliorate the problem, emphasis has been given on expansion of roads, construction of flyovers, and streamlining traffic movements. The decision to prohibit private vehicles from running on alternate days marks a departure from the past as it implicitly recognises the presence of excess vehicles in Delhi and plans to cut it down substantially.

The odd–even formula has been applied in several metropolitan cities around the world in various forms and its impact has been mixed. A regulation in 1989 by the city administration of Mexico banned each vehicle from driving on a specific day of the week. While reviewing the impact of the policy Eskeland and Feyzioglu (1995: 1) make the following observations:

The regulation has been both popular and controversial: some feel it is a reasonable concession from each car owner—aimed to alleviate congestion and pollution problems. Others have felt that it is inefficient and unfair; inefficient in the way most rationing devices are inefficient, unfair because it will be particularly costly to some—easily avoided or accommodated by others. Finally, some feel that the regulation may be so inefficient that it is counterproductive—increasing the levels of congestion and pollution—because some have purchased additional cars to circumvent the ban, and end up increasing their driving. The authors … find evidence in support of the latter view.

The policy of banning odd- and even-numbered vehicles on specific days has prompted households in Beijing to go for a second car with a different registration number so that they can drive everyday by alternate use of two cars. According to Hao et al (2011) about 30% car sales in Beijing is to satisfy the need for second car with the intention of avoiding the vehicle use regulations.

The odd–even formula has the advantage of reducing the number of vehicles in a city immediately. The immediate effect of regulating odd–even vehicles in Beijing was reduction in vehicle flow by 21% and increase in average fleet speed by 27% (Hao et al 2011). The rebound effect of increase in vehicle ownership however partly offset the policy’s effects on reduction of total vehicle use.

The odd–even formula is a short-term measure to reduce the number of vehicles immediately. Seen from this perspective, the decision of the Delhi government to give it a trial run for 15 days (1–15 January) is a welcome decision. Some of the nagging issues in this venture however are: (i) the large number of vehicles entering Delhi from neighbouring areas, (ii) concessions given to emergency situations for Delhi households, (iii) funding of additional cost to implement the policy, and (iv) perception of alienation among people. Given its coercive CAC nature, it does not give much freedom to people and could be counter-productive.[vii] Thus the long-term solution to the problem has to be different and based on economic incentives.

Internalising Externalities

The social cost being higher than private cost in the case of private vehicles calls for internalising externalities. This could be achieved by a two-pronged strategy of (i) imposition of congestion tax on private vehicles, and (ii) subsidy on public transport. Such a strategy will alter the cost–benefit scenarios of private and public vehicles and provide economic incentives to people to alter their mode of transport. An important advantage of economic incentives over CAC measures is the “double dividend”—congestion tax will reduce the number of vehicles and simultaneously generate revenues which can be used for strengthening public transport and smooth flow of vehicles. It could be a win–win situation for stakeholders. The government will gain additional revenue by means of congestion tax which it can utilise for subsidy on public transport. Private vehicle users will gain by saving on time and fuel cost, as fleet speed will improve with reduction in number of vehicles. The general public will gain through reduction in health cost as air pollution levels decline.

The tax imposed on private vehicles has to be calibrated in such a manner that it makes people perceive that the private cost of using a private vehicle is high enough and it is profitable to use public transport. Imposition of taxes on private vehicles calls for a bold decision by the government, but it could be geared to a populist measure as there are two advantages to the government, namely, (i) it is progressive in nature in the sense that poorer households are exempted automatically, and (ii) public transport is made cheaper, adequate, reliable and safe. In fact it may provide adequate funds to the government to integrate bus, metro and local railway services.

The imposition of congestion tax on private vehicles provides justification for imposition of a similar tax on private vehicles entering Delhi from neighbouring areas. The green tax imposed on commercial vehicles entering Delhi could be seen as a precursor in this respect.

A tentative calculation implying the fact that Delhi is sitting on a goldmine can be seen from the following. If we take a conservative estimate of congestion tax of Rs 1,000 per month for cars and jeeps, and Rs 500 per month for motorcycles and scooters, it would generate a revenue of about Rs 563.12 crore per month or Rs 6,757.44 crore per annum. If we add the tax collected from vehicles entering Delhi from adjoining areas, this figure will go up substantially. One can imagine to what extent public transport can be improved with such amounts of funding, and the commitment to a cleaner environment be met.

Notes

[i] The total number of vehicles in Delhi as of March 2015 is 88.3 lakh of which 96% are private vehicles (Government of Delhi 2015). Fifty percent of these private vehicles amount 42.4 lakh.

[ii] The Central Pollution Control Board (CPCB) has specified norms for noise level for four different categories, namely, industrial, commercial, residential and silence zones. For residential areas acceptable standard is 55 decibels during daytime and 45 decibels during night night. According to Centre for Science and Environment (CSE) noise level in the Delhi is in excess of 100 decibels in many areas. The adverse health effects of high noise pollution could be hearing loss, sleep disorder, heart ailments, and general annoyance (CSE 2011).

[iii] Reported in Economic Times, 3 December 2015, http://articles.economictimes.indiatimes.com/2015-12-03/news/68741891_1_centre-and-city-government-delhi-high-court-traffic-police.

[iv] In fact, one can notice acceleration in growth rate since 2001–02. According to Economic Survey of Delhi there were 201 vehicles per 1,000 persons in 1991–92 which increased to 244 in 2000–01, considered to be moderate compared to the growth in the subsequent period. When we fitted a piece-wise linear regression, we find the trend growth rate in number of vehicles per 1,000 persons to be 4.8% per annum during 2001–02 to 2014–15 compared to 2.4% per annum during 1990–91 to 2000–01.

[v] In fact, there are many households with multiple private vehicles. Moreover, one can notice certain qualitative changes in vehicle composition with the proportion of high-end cars increasing rapidly.

[vi] The working loss in 2014–15 is to the tune of Rs 1,011.38 crore.

[vii] According to the Centre for Science and Environment (CSE) the congestion level and associated problems in most localities in Delhi are alarming (as reported in Hindustan Times, 20 August 2015, http://www.hindustantimes.com/delhi/congestion-pollution-twin-demons-in-south-delhi-colonies-cse/story-w1YF522kCnfFR7NLK6pzZM.html). Purchase of multiple vehicles by households will further aggravate it.  

References

Banerjee, D, S K Chakraborty, S Bhattacharyya, and A Gangopadhyay (2008): “Evaluation and Analysis of Road Traffic Noise in Asansol: An Industrial Town of Eastern India,” International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health, Vol 5, No 3, pp 165–71.

CSE (2011): CSE Surveys Noise Pollution in Delhi, viewed on 11 December 2015, http://www.cseindia.org/content/cse-surveys-noise-pollution-delhi.

Eskeland, Gunnar S and Tarhan Feyzioglu (1995): “Rationing Can Backfire: The ‘Day Without a car’ in Mexico City,” Policy Research Working Paper 1554, World Bank.

Gurjar, B R, J A van Aardenne and J Lelieveld (2004): “Emission Estimates and Trends (1990–2000) for Megacity Delhi and Implications,” Atmospheric Environment, Vol 38, No 33, pp 5663–81.

Hao, Han, Hewu Wang, Minggao Ouyang (2011): “Comparison of policies on vehicle ownership and use between Beijing and Shanghai and their impacts on fuel consumption by passenger vehicles,” Energy Policy, Vol 39, pp 1016–21.

Government of Delhi (2015): Economic Survey of Delhi, 2014–15.

Kathuria, Vinish (2005): “Vehicular Pollution Control in Delhi,” Economic and Political Weekly, Vol 40, No 18, 30 April.

Small, Kenneth A and Erik T Verhoef (2007): Economics of Urban Transportation, Routledge: New York.

 
Back to Top